In practice, the annualized realized variance is defined by the sum of the square of discrete-sampling log-return of the specified underlying asset. In other words, if there are n + 1 {\displaystyle n+1} sampling points of the underlying prices, says S t 0 , S t 2 , … , S t n {\displaystyle S_{t_{0}},S_{t_{2}},\dots ,S_{t_{n}}} observed at time t i {\displaystyle t_{i}} where 0 ≤ t i − 1 < t i ≤ T {\displaystyle 0\leq t_{i-1}<t_{i}\leq T} for all i ∈ { 1 , … , n } {\displaystyle i\in \{1,\dots ,n\}} , then the realized variance denoted by R V d {\displaystyle RV_{d}} is valued of the form
where
If one puts
then payoffs at expiry for the call and put options written on R V d {\displaystyle RV_{d}} (or just variance call and put) are
and
respectively.
Note that the annualized realized variance can also be defined through continuous sampling, which resulted in the quadratic variation of the underlying price. That is, if we suppose that σ ( t ) {\displaystyle \sigma (t)} determines the instantaneous volatility of the price process, then
defines the continuous-sampling annualized realized variance which is also proved to be the limit in the probability of the discrete form1 i.e.
However, this approach is only adopted to approximate the discrete one since the contracts involving realized variance are practically quoted in terms of the discrete sampling.
Suppose that under a risk-neutral measure Q {\displaystyle \mathbb {Q} } the underlying asset price S = ( S t ) 0 ≤ t ≤ T {\displaystyle S=(S_{t})_{0\leq t\leq T}} solves the time-varying Black–Scholes model as follows:
where:
ฺBy this setting, in the case of variance call, its fair price at time t 0 {\displaystyle t_{0}} denoted by C t 0 var {\displaystyle C_{t_{0}}^{\text{var}}} can be attained by the expected present value of its payoff function i.e.
where R V ( ⋅ ) = R V d {\displaystyle RV_{(\cdot )}=RV_{d}} for the discrete sampling while R V ( ⋅ ) = R V c {\displaystyle RV_{(\cdot )}=RV_{c}} for the continuous sampling. And by put-call parity we also get the put value once C t 0 var {\displaystyle C_{t_{0}}^{\text{var}}} is known. The solution can be approached analytically with the similar methodology to that of the Black–Scholes derivation once the probability density function of R V ( ⋅ ) {\displaystyle RV_{(\cdot )}} is perceived, or by means of some approximation schemes, like, the Monte Carlo method.
Barndorff-Nielsen, Ole E.; Shephard, Neil (May 2002). "Econometric analysis of realised volatility and its use in estimating stochastic volatility models". Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B. 64 (2): 253–280. doi:10.1111/1467-9868.00336. S2CID 122716443. /wiki/Ole_Barndorff-Nielsen ↩