An alternating-offers protocol induces a sequential game. A natural question is what outcomes can be attained in an equilibrium of this game. At first glance, the first player has the power to make a very selfish offer. For example, in the Dividing the Dollar game, player #1 can offer to give only 1% of the money to player #2, and threaten that "if you do not accept, I will refuse all offers from now on, and both of us will get 0". But this is a non-credible threat, since if player #2 refuses and makes a counter-offer (e.g. give 2% of the money to player #1), then it is better for player #1 to accept. Therefore, a natural question is: what outcomes are a subgame perfect equilibrium (SPE) of this game? This question has been studied in various settings.
Ariel Rubinstein studied a setting in which the negotiation is on how to divide $1 between the two players.1 Each player in turn can offer any partition. The players bear a cost for each round of negotiation. The cost can be presented in two ways:
Rubinstein and Wolinsky2 studied a market in which there are many players, partitioned into two types (e.g. "buyers" and "sellers"). Pairs of players of different types are brought together randomly, and initiate a sequential-bargaining process over the division of a surplus (as in the Divide the Dollar game). If they reach an agreement, they leave the market; otherwise, they remain in the market and wait for the next match. The steady-state equilibrium in this market it is quite different than competitive equilibrium in standard markets (e.g. Fisher market or Arrow–Debreu market).
Fudenberg and Tirole3 study sequential bargaining between a buyer and a seller who have incomplete information, i.e., they do not know the valuation of their partner. They focus on a two-turn game (i.e., the seller has exactly two opportunities to sell the item to the buyer). Both players prefer a trade today than the same trade tomorrow. They analyze the Perfect Bayesian equilibrium (PBE) in this game, if the seller's valuation is known, then the PBE is generically unique; but if both valuations are private, then there are multiple PBE. Some surprising findings, that follow from the information transfer and the lack of commitment, are:
Grossman and Perry4 study sequential bargaining between a buyer and a seller over an item price, where the buyer knows the gains-from-trade but the seller does not. They consider an infinite-turn game with time discounting. They show that, under some weak assumptions, there exists a unique perfect sequential equilibrium, in which:
Nejat Anbarci5 studied a setting with a finite number of outcomes, where each of the two agents may have a different preference order over the outcomes. The protocol rules disallow repeating the same offer twice. In any such game, there is a unique SPE. It is always Pareto optimal; it is always one of the two Pareto-optimal options of which rankings by the players are the closest. It can be found by finding the smallest integer k for which the sets of k best options of the two players have a non-empty intersection. For example, if the rankings are a>b>c>d and c>b>a>d, then the unique SPE is b (with k=2). If the rankings are a>b>c>d and d>c>b>a, then the SPE is either b or c (with k=3).
In a later study, Anbarci6 studies several schemes for two agents who have to select an arbitrator from a given set of candidates:
In all schemes, if the options are uniformly distributed over the bargaining set and their number approaches infinity, then the unique SPE outcome converges to the Equal-Area solution of the cooperative bargaining problem.
Erlich, Hazon and Kraus7 study the Alternating Offers protocol in several informational settings:
The Dividing-the-Dollar game has been studied in several laboratory experiments. In general, subjects behave quite differently from the unique SPE. Subjects' behavior depends on the number of turns, their experience with the game, and their beliefs about fairness. There have been multiple experiments.8
A field study was done by Backus, Blake, Larsen and Tadelis.9 They studied back-and-forth sequential bargaining in over 25 million listings from the Best Offer platform of eBay. Their main findings are:
They also report some findings that cannot be rationalized by the existing theories:
They suggest that these findings can be explained by behavioral norms.
Rubinstein, Ariel (1982). "Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model". Econometrica. 50 (1): 97–109. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.295.1434. doi:10.2307/1912531. JSTOR 1912531. S2CID 14827857. /wiki/CiteSeerX_(identifier) ↩
Rubinstein, Ariel; Wolinsky, Asher (1985). "Equilibrium in a Market with Sequential Bargaining". Econometrica. 53 (5): 1133–1150. doi:10.2307/1911015. ISSN 0012-9682. JSTOR 1911015. S2CID 7553405. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1911015 ↩
Fudenberg, Drew; Tirole, Jean (1983). "Sequential Bargaining with Incomplete Information". The Review of Economic Studies. 50 (2): 221–247. doi:10.2307/2297414. ISSN 0034-6527. JSTOR 2297414. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2297414 ↩
Grossman, Sanford J; Perry, Motty (1986-06-01). "Sequential bargaining under asymmetric information". Journal of Economic Theory. 39 (1): 120–154. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(86)90023-2. ISSN 0022-0531. S2CID 154201801. https://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531%2886%2990023-2 ↩
Anbarci, N. (1993-02-01). "Noncooperative Foundations of the Area Monotonic Solution". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 108 (1): 245–258. doi:10.2307/2118502. ISSN 0033-5533. JSTOR 2118502. https://academic.oup.com/qje/article-abstract/108/1/245/1898523 ↩
Anbarci, Nejat (2006-08-01). "Finite Alternating-Move Arbitration Schemes and the Equal Area Solution". Theory and Decision. 61 (1): 21–50. doi:10.1007/s11238-005-4748-9. ISSN 0040-5833. S2CID 122355062. http://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1062&context=economics_wps ↩
Erlich, Sefi; Hazon, Noam; Kraus, Sarit (2018-05-02). "Negotiation Strategies for Agents with Ordinal Preferences". arXiv:1805.00913 [cs.GT]. /wiki/ArXiv_(identifier) ↩
Güth, Werner; Schmittberger, Rolf; Schwarze, Bernd (1982-12-01). "An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 3 (4): 367–388. doi:10.1016/0167-2681(82)90011-7. ISSN 0167-2681.Binmore, K.; Shaked, A.; Sutton, J. (1985). "Testing Noncooperative Bargaining Theory: A Preliminary Study". The American Economic Review. 75 (5): 1178–1180. ISSN 0002-8282. JSTOR 1818658.Güth, Werner; Tietz, Reinhard (1988). "Ultimatum Bargaining for a Shrinking Cake — an Experimental Analysis —". In Tietz, Reinhard; Albers, Wulf; Selten, Reinhard (eds.). Bounded Rational Behavior in Experimental Games and Markets. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems. Vol. 314. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer. pp. 111–128. doi:10.1007/978-3-642-48356-1_9. ISBN 978-3-642-48356-1.Neelin, Janet; Sonnenschein, Hugo; Spiegel, Matthew (1988). "A Further Test of Noncooperative Bargaining Theory: Comment". The American Economic Review. 78 (4): 824–836. ISSN 0002-8282. JSTOR 1811179.Ochs, Jack; Roth, Alvin E. (1989). "An Experimental Study of Sequential Bargaining". The American Economic Review. 79 (3): 355–384. ISSN 0002-8282. JSTOR 1806850.Güth, Werner; Tietz, Reinhard (1990-09-01). "Ultimatum bargaining behavior: A survey and comparison of experimental results". Journal of Economic Psychology. 11 (3): 417–449. doi:10.1016/0167-4870(90)90021-Z. ISSN 0167-4870. 978-3-642-48356-1 ↩
Backus, Matthew; Blake, Thomas; Larsen, Brad; Tadelis, Steven (2020-08-01). "Sequential Bargaining in the Field: Evidence from Millions of Online Bargaining Interactions". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 135 (3): 1319–1361. doi:10.1093/qje/qjaa003. ISSN 0033-5533. https://academic.oup.com/qje/article/135/3/1319/5721265 ↩
"Game-Theoretic Models of Bargaining | Microeconomics". Cambridge University Press. Retrieved 2021-02-05. https://www.cambridge.org/us/academic/subjects/economics/microeconomics/game-theoretic-models-bargaining,%20https://www.cambridge.org/us/academic/subjects/economics/microeconomics ↩