The marginal revenue product of labour M R P L {\displaystyle MRP_{L}} is the increase in revenue per unit increase in the variable input = Δ T R Δ L {\displaystyle {\frac {\Delta TR}{\Delta L}}}
Here:
[This page is incomplete. Please define each and every variable and include their dimension]
The change in output is not limited to that directly attributable to the additional worker. Assuming that the firm is operating with diminishing marginal returns then the addition of an extra worker reduces the average productivity of every other worker (and every other worker affects the marginal productivity of the additional worker).
The firm is modeled as choosing to add units of labor until the M R P {\displaystyle MRP} equals the wage rate w {\displaystyle w} — mathematically until
Under perfect competition, marginal revenue product is equal to marginal physical product (extra unit of good produced as a result of a new employment) multiplied by price.
This is because the firm in perfect competition is a price taker. It does not have to lower the price in order to sell additional units of the good.
Firms operating as monopolies or in imperfect competition face downward-sloping demand curves. To sell extra units of output, they would have to lower their output's price. Under such market conditions, marginal revenue product will not equal M P P × Price {\displaystyle MPP\times {\text{Price}}} . This is because the firm is not able to sell output at a fixed price per unit. Thus the M R P {\displaystyle MRP} curve of a firm in monopoly or in imperfect competition will slope downwards, when plotted against labor usage, at a faster rate than in perfect specific competition.
Daniel S. Hamermesh. 1986. The demand for labor in the long run. Handbook of Labor Economics (Orley Ashenfelter and Richard Layard, ed.) p. 429. ↩