In microeconomics, the expenditure function represents the minimum spending required to reach a specified utility level given a utility function and prices of goods. Formally, it minimizes total expenditure p·x over all consumption bundles x that yield at least the desired utility u*. Here, p is the price vector, and the set of bundles satisfies preferences ensuring utility ≥ u*. This is equivalent to choosing quantities x₁*, ..., xₙ* to minimize costs while maintaining u(x₁, ..., xₙ) ≥ u*. The expenditure function then equals the total cost of these optimal quantities, expressed as e(p, u*) = p₁x₁* + ... + pₙxₙ*.
Properties
Suppose u {\displaystyle u} is a continuous utility function representing a locally non-satiated preference relation on R + n {\displaystyle {\textbf {R}}_{+}^{n}} . Then e ( p , u ∗ ) {\displaystyle e(p,u^{*})} is
- Homogeneous of degree one in p: for all and λ > 0 {\displaystyle \lambda >0} , e ( λ p , u ) = λ e ( p , u ) ; {\displaystyle e(\lambda p,u)=\lambda e(p,u);}
- Continuous in p {\displaystyle p} and u ; {\displaystyle u;}
- Nondecreasing in p {\displaystyle p} and strictly increasing in u {\displaystyle u} provided p ≫ 0 ; {\displaystyle p\gg 0;}
- Concave in p {\displaystyle p}
- If the utility function is strictly quasi-concave, there is Shephard's lemma
Proofs
(1) As in the above proposition, note that
e ( λ p , u ) = min x ∈ R + n : u ( x ) ≥ u {\displaystyle e(\lambda p,u)=\min _{x\in \mathbb {R} _{+}^{n}:u(x)\geq u}} λ p ⋅ x = λ min x ∈ R + n : u ( x ) ≥ u {\displaystyle \lambda p\cdot x=\lambda \min _{x\in \mathbb {R} _{+}^{n}:u(x)\geq u}} p ⋅ x = λ e ( p , u ) {\displaystyle p\cdot x=\lambda e(p,u)}
(2) Continue on the domain e {\displaystyle e} : R + + N ∗ R → R {\displaystyle {\textbf {R}}_{++}^{N}*{\textbf {R}}\rightarrow {\textbf {R}}}
(3) Let p ′ > p {\displaystyle p^{\prime }>p} and suppose x ∈ h ( p ′ , u ) {\displaystyle x\in h(p^{\prime },u)} . Then u ( h ) ≥ u {\displaystyle u(h)\geq u} , and e ( p ′ , u ) = p ′ ⋅ x ≥ p ⋅ x {\displaystyle e(p^{\prime },u)=p^{\prime }\cdot x\geq p\cdot x} . It follows immediately that e ( p , u ) ≤ e ( p ′ , u ) {\displaystyle e(p,u)\leq e(p^{\prime },u)} .
For the second statement, suppose to the contrary that for some u ′ > u {\displaystyle u^{\prime }>u} , e ( p , u ′ ) ≤ e ( p , u ) {\displaystyle e(p,u^{\prime })\leq e(p,u)} Than, for some x ∈ h ( p , u ) {\displaystyle x\in h(p,u)} , u ( x ) = u ′ > u {\displaystyle u(x)=u^{\prime }>u} , which contradicts the "no excess utility" conclusion of the previous proposition
(4) Let t ∈ ( 0 , 1 ) {\displaystyle t\in (0,1)} and suppose x ∈ h ( t p + ( 1 − t ) p ′ ) {\displaystyle x\in h(tp+(1-t)p^{\prime })} . Then, p ⋅ x ≥ e ( p , u ) {\displaystyle p\cdot x\geq e(p,u)} and p ′ ⋅ x ≥ e ( p ′ , u ) {\displaystyle p^{\prime }\cdot x\geq e(p^{\prime },u)} , so e ( t p + ( 1 − t ) p ′ , u ) = ( t p + ( 1 − t ) p ′ ) ⋅ x ≥ {\displaystyle e(tp+(1-t)p^{\prime },u)=(tp+(1-t)p^{\prime })\cdot x\geq } t e ( p , u ) + ( 1 − t ) e ( p ′ , u ) {\displaystyle te(p,u)+(1-t)e(p^{\prime },u)} .
(5) δ ( p 0 , u 0 ) δ p i = x i h ( p 0 , u 0 ) {\displaystyle {\frac {\delta (p^{0},u^{0})}{\delta p_{i}}}=x_{i}^{h}(p^{0},u^{0})}
Expenditure and indirect utility
The expenditure function is the inverse of the indirect utility function when the prices are kept constant. I.e, for every price vector p {\displaystyle p} and income level I {\displaystyle I} :1: 106
e ( p , v ( p , I ) ) ≡ I {\displaystyle e(p,v(p,I))\equiv I}There is a duality relationship between the expenditure function and the utility function. If given a specific regular quasi-concave utility function, the corresponding price is homogeneous, and the utility is monotonically increasing expenditure function, conversely, the given price is homogeneous, and the utility is monotonically increasing expenditure function will generate the regular quasi-concave utility function. In addition to the property that prices are once homogeneous and utility is monotonically increasing, the expenditure function usually assumes
- Is a non-negative function, i.e., E ( P ⋅ u ) > O ; {\displaystyle E(P\cdot u)>O;}
- For P, it is non-decreasing, i.e., E ( p 1 u ) > E ( p 2 u ) , u > O p l > p 2 > O N {\displaystyle E(p^{1}u)>E(p^{2}u),u>Op^{l}>p^{2}>O_{N}} ;
- E(Pu) is a concave function. That is, e ( n p l + ( 1 − n ) p 2 ) u ) > λ E ( p 1 u ) ( 1 − n ) E ( p 2 u ) y > 0 {\displaystyle e(np^{l}+(1-n)p^{2})u)>\lambda E(p^{1}u)(1-n)E(p^{2}u)y>0} O < λ < 1 p l ≥ O N p 2 ≥ O N {\displaystyle O<\lambda <1p^{l}\geq O_{N}p^{2}\geq O_{N}}
Expenditure function is an important theoretical method to study consumer behavior. Expenditure function is very similar to cost function in production theory. Dual to the utility maximization problem is the cost minimization problem 23
Example
Suppose the utility function is the Cobb-Douglas function u ( x 1 , x 2 ) = x 1 .6 x 2 .4 , {\displaystyle u(x_{1},x_{2})=x_{1}^{.6}x_{2}^{.4},} which generates the demand functions4
x 1 ( p 1 , p 2 , I ) = .6 I p 1 a n d x 2 ( p 1 , p 2 , I ) = .4 I p 2 , {\displaystyle x_{1}(p_{1},p_{2},I)={\frac {.6I}{p_{1}}}\;\;\;\;{\rm {and}}\;\;\;x_{2}(p_{1},p_{2},I)={\frac {.4I}{p_{2}}},}where I {\displaystyle I} is the consumer's income. One way to find the expenditure function is to first find the indirect utility function and then invert it. The indirect utility function v ( p 1 , p 2 , I ) {\displaystyle v(p_{1},p_{2},I)} is found by replacing the quantities in the utility function with the demand functions thus:
v ( p 1 , p 2 , I ) = u ( x 1 ∗ , x 2 ∗ ) = ( x 1 ∗ ) .6 ( x 2 ∗ ) .4 = ( .6 I p 1 ) .6 ( .4 I p 2 ) .4 = ( .6 .6 × .4 .4 ) I .6 + .4 p 1 − .6 p 2 − .4 = K p 1 − .6 p 2 − .4 I , {\displaystyle v(p_{1},p_{2},I)=u(x_{1}^{*},x_{2}^{*})=(x_{1}^{*})^{.6}(x_{2}^{*})^{.4}=\left({\frac {.6I}{p_{1}}}\right)^{.6}\left({\frac {.4I}{p_{2}}}\right)^{.4}=(.6^{.6}\times .4^{.4})I^{.6+.4}p_{1}^{-.6}p_{2}^{-.4}=Kp_{1}^{-.6}p_{2}^{-.4}I,}where K = ( .6 .6 × .4 .4 ) . {\displaystyle K=(.6^{.6}\times .4^{.4}).} Then since e ( p 1 , p 2 , u ) = e ( p 1 , p 2 , v ( p 1 , p 2 , I ) ) = I {\displaystyle e(p_{1},p_{2},u)=e(p_{1},p_{2},v(p_{1},p_{2},I))=I} when the consumer optimizes, we can invert the indirect utility function to find the expenditure function:
e ( p 1 , p 2 , u ) = ( 1 / K ) p 1 .6 p 2 .4 u , {\displaystyle e(p_{1},p_{2},u)=(1/K)p_{1}^{.6}p_{2}^{.4}u,}Alternatively, the expenditure function can be found by solving the problem of minimizing ( p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 ) {\displaystyle (p_{1}x_{1}+p_{2}x_{2})} subject to the constraint u ( x 1 , x 2 ) ≥ u ∗ . {\displaystyle u(x_{1},x_{2})\geq u^{*}.} This yields conditional demand functions x 1 ∗ ( p 1 , p 2 , u ∗ ) {\displaystyle x_{1}^{*}(p_{1},p_{2},u^{*})} and x 2 ∗ ( p 1 , p 2 , u ∗ ) {\displaystyle x_{2}^{*}(p_{1},p_{2},u^{*})} and the expenditure function is then
e ( p 1 , p 2 , u ∗ ) = p 1 x 1 ∗ + p 2 x 2 ∗ {\displaystyle e(p_{1},p_{2},u^{*})=p_{1}x_{1}^{*}+p_{2}x_{2}^{*}}See also
- Expenditure minimization problem
- Hicksian demand function
- Slutsky equation
- Utility maximization problem
- Budget constraint
- Consumption set
- Shephard's lemma
Further reading
- Mas-Colell, Andreu; Whinston, Michael D.; Green, Jerry R. (2007). Microeconomic Theory. pp. 59–60. ISBN 978-0-19-510268-0.
- Mathis, Stephen A.; Koscianski, Janet (2002). Microeconomic Theory: An Integrated Approach. Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall. pp. 132–133. ISBN 0-13-011418-9.
- Varian, Hal R. (1984). Microeconomic Analysis (Second ed.). New York: W. W. Norton. pp. 121–123. ISBN 0-393-95282-7.
References
Varian, Hal (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (Third ed.). New York: Norton. ISBN 0-393-95735-7. 0-393-95735-7 ↩
Jing ji xue da ci dian. Xiaomin Liang, 梁小民. (Di 1 ban ed.). Beijing Shi: Tuan jie chu ban she. 1994. ISBN 7-80061-954-0. OCLC 34287945.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: others (link) 7-80061-954-0 ↩
"CONSUMER CHOICE AND DUALITY" (PDF). 23 February 2024. http://www2.econ.iastate.edu/classes/econ501/Hallam/documents/DualConsumer.pdf ↩
Varian, H. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (3rd ed.). New York: W. W. Norton., pp. 111, has the general formula. https://archive.org/details/microeconomicana00vari_0 ↩